ELASTICITY OF DEMAND AND SUPPLY
As we learned in our discussion of demand, the
price of a commodity can greatly influence our behavior as consumers. We want
to take a closer look at consumer behavior. How responsive is consumers’ demand
to change in the price of food. Medicine, or luxury items such as cars and the
like. The measure of our responsiveness to change in price is called price elasticity of demand.
In this chapter, we will study the price elasticity of demand, its effects, and
its determinants.
We should review the basic concept of demand
The
law of demand expresses the relationship between price and quantity demanded.
When the price of a good is decreased, a greater quantity demanded. When the
price of a good is increased, a lesser quantity of it is demanded. This law
assumes that all other factors underlying demand are held constant.
Introduction to Elasticity of Demand
Although
the law of Demand states that as the price of a good decreases, more of it is
demanded, the degree of responsiveness to a price change will depend on:
·
How
important the commodity is to the buyer’s well-being; for example, changes in
the price of medicine, food, stereo,
car, or hamburgers will create different responses.
·
The
relative degree of the price of the commodity with respect to the purchaser’s
resources or income.
·
The
availability of substitute goods.
The degree of
sensitivity of consumer behavior to price changes is called the Price
Elasticity of Demand.
1.
Demand
is Elastic when the relative change in the quantity demanded of a commodity is
greater that the relative change in price.
2.
Demand
is inelastic when the relative change in the quantity demanded of commodity is
less than the relative change in the price.
You should notice in
the definitions of elastic and inelastic demand that the phrase relative change is important.
Elasticity is a measure of the sensitivity or the responsiveness of changes in
quantities demanded resulting from changes in price. This responsiveness refers
to the degree to which the quantity demanded changes compared to the amount the
price changes.
As
consumers, the fact that we demand goods involves making expenditures when we
purchase the goods. Our expenditures as buyers constitute receipts of revenue
for sellers, where revenue is defined as the amount of money received from the
sale of a commodity. As the first step in explaining the concept of elasticity,
we will use the demand schedule to derive a total revenue schedule. Then we
will illustrate total revenue graphically.
The total revenue schedule
A demand schedule is a schedule which shows the quantity of a good that will be demanded at each price. A total revenue schedule can derived from demand schedule simply by multiplying the quantity of the good that would be demanded at each price, by the price. Therefore, for every price on a demand schedule there is a total revenue value. Consider the following demand schedule: ( see table 1 )
Table 1
A total revenue
schedule
(1) |
(2) |
(3) |
Price |
Quantity Demanded |
Total Revenue |
8.00 |
1 |
P8.00 |
6.00 |
2 |
12.00 |
4.00 |
3 |
12.00 |
2.00 |
4 |
8.00 |
Every
point on a demand curve represents a unique price and a unique quantity, if you
draw lines. If you draw lines connecting any point on a demand curve to the
price and quantity axes, you will have a negative slope, means line is in
decline position. ( see figure 1 )
An important
implication of elasticity is the effect on total revenue when price increases
or decreases. Let us first look at the changes in total revenue caused by a
price change in the quantity where demand is elastic. Remember in this case,
changes in the quantity demanded are greater relatively than the changes in
price.
Elastic Demand and Total Revenue
When
demand is elastic, a fall in price results in an increase in total revenue.
This is because the loss in revenue due to a lower price per unit is relatively
less than the gain in revenue due to the greater quantity of sales. In other
words, the response in terms of quantity demanded is very high.
When
demand is Inelastic, an increase in price results in a decrease in total
revenue. This is because the gain in total revenue resulting from the higher
unit price is relatively less than the loss in revenue resulting from decline
in quantity sold.
Inelastic Demand and Total Revenue
When
demand is inelastic, a decline in price will cause total revenue to decrease.
The small increase in quantity
purchased will not be enough to make up for the
decline in revenue per unit; therefore, total revenue decrease
When
demand is inelastic, an increase in price will cause total revenue to increase.
The gain in total revenue resulting from the higher unit price is greater than
the loss in revenue resulting from the fall in sales.
Unitary Elastic Demand and Total Revenue
There
is a special case called unitary elastic, this occurs when an increase or
decrease in price does not change total revenue. In the case of Unitary
elastic, the loss of revenues due to the lower price will just be offset by the
increase in revenue, due to a larger quantity purchased. The gain in revenues
due to
the higher price will just be offset by the
decrease in revenues caused by the smaller quantity purchased.
It is very important that you understand
elasticity and its effect on total revenue. You will find a chart which
summarizes the three cases we have just discussed.
Summary of Elasticity of Demand and Total
Revenues
IF |
THEN |
AND |
DEMAND IS |
Price
Decrease |
Quantity demand increase |
Total revenue increase |
Elastic |
Price Decrease |
Quantity demanded Increase |
Total revenue Decrease |
Inelastic |
Price Increase |
Quantity Demanded Decrease |
Total Revenue Increase |
Inelastic |
Price Increase |
Quantity Demanded Decrease |
Total Revenue Decrease |
Elastic |
Price Increase |
Quantity Demanded Decrease |
Total Revenue Constant |
Unitary Elastic |
Price Decrease |
Quantity Demanded Increase |
Total Revenue Constant |
Unitary Elastic |
Finally,
lets look at two special cases of elasticity of demand. These two extreme or
limiting cases are known as perfectly
inelastic demand and perfectly elastic demand.
When
a very large relative change in price causes only a slight change in relative quantity
demanded, demand is inelastic. The
extreme or limiting cases occurs when there is no change in quantity demanded no matter what the change
in price. This situation is shown by a perfectly
inelastic demand curve as in figure 4.
So far we have been speaking about elasticity
of demand in general terms. It is much more convenient to have a quantitative
measure of elasticity. This is achieved by computing the coefficient of
elasticity. The two coefficient of elasticity are as follows:
Economic
Approach
Coe= Qd2 - Qd1 P2-P1
------------- ---------
Qd2 + Qd1 P2+P1
------------- ---------
2
2
whereas
Qd1 – Original Quantity
demand
Qd2 – New Quantity demand
P1 – Original Price
P2 – New Price
Example:
The
price of Pandesal per piece is P1.25. it
leads to daily total sales of 25,000 pieces among the Valenzuela area. The
price then rises to P1.50 per piece which leads to a total sales of 22,350
pieces or a reduction in quantity by 2,650 pieces. From the given data, what is
the consumer response with respect to the changes in price.
Solution:
Economics Method
Given:
Q1 – 25,000
Q2 – 22,350
P1 – P1.25
P2 – P1.50
22,350 - 25,000 1.50 – 1.25 2,650 .25
---------------------- ÷
---------------- =
--------------- ÷ -------
22,350 + 25,000 1.50 + 1.25 47,350 2.75
---------------------- --------------- --------------- -------
2 2 2 2
= 2,650 .25
-----------
X ---------
23,675
1.375
= 3,643.75
--------------
5,918.75
=
.6 inelastic
Statistic Approach
∆ in QD ∆ in Price
------------------- ÷ ----------------------
Q1 P1
Whereas:
∆ -
change
∆
in QD - Qd2 - Qd1
∆
in Price - P2 - P1
2,650
.25 3,312.5
=
------------- X -------- = --------------
25,000 1.25
6,250
=
.53 inelastic
In the following demand schedule for banana per
piece, the elasticity are derived the same way using the economic method.
Table 3
Demand schedule for
banana per piece
Price per piece |
Quantity demanded per
week |
Elasticity
coefficient |
.50 |
1 |
|
.45 |
2 |
6.33 elastic |
.40 |
3 |
3.40 elastic |
.35 |
4 |
2.14 elastic |
.30 |
5 |
1.44 elastic |
.25 |
6 |
1.00 unitary |
.20 |
7 |
.69 inelastic |
.15 |
8 |
.47 inelastic |
.10 |
9 |
.29 inelastic |
Note that this demand curve has an elastic,
unitary, and inelastic portion. We can read this from the column showing
coefficient of elasticity.
Interpreting the Coefficient of Elasticity
When demand is elastic and the
elasticity coefficient is greater than 1, the percentage change in quantity
demanded is larger that the percentage change in price
When the demand is inelastic, the
elasticity coefficient is less than 1. this is because a percentage change in
price results in a smaller percentage change in quantity demanded
When demand is unitary, the elasticity coefficient is 1. this is because a percentage change in price results in an equal percentage change in quantity demanded .
Related Topics
·
Introduction of Microeconomics
·
Scarcity
·
Production possibilities
·
Basic Economic Problem
·
Circular
flow of Economic Activity
·
Common
types of Economic System
·
Economic resources
·
Demand supply and markets
·
Demand
·
Supply
·
Elasticity of demand and supply
·
Market
·
Surplus
·
Shortage